Production investment behaviour : Application to six EEC-countries (Tilburg Studies in Economics)

個数:

Production investment behaviour : Application to six EEC-countries (Tilburg Studies in Economics)

  • 提携先の海外書籍取次会社に在庫がございます。通常3週間で発送いたします。
    重要ご説明事項
    1. 納期遅延や、ご入手不能となる場合が若干ございます。
    2. 複数冊ご注文の場合は、ご注文数量が揃ってからまとめて発送いたします。
    3. 美品のご指定は承りかねます。

    ●3Dセキュア導入とクレジットカードによるお支払いについて
  • 【入荷遅延について】
    世界情勢の影響により、海外からお取り寄せとなる洋書・洋古書の入荷が、表示している標準的な納期よりも遅延する場合がございます。
    おそれいりますが、あらかじめご了承くださいますようお願い申し上げます。
  • ◆画像の表紙や帯等は実物とは異なる場合があります。
  • ◆ウェブストアでの洋書販売価格は、弊社店舗等での販売価格とは異なります。
    また、洋書販売価格は、ご注文確定時点での日本円価格となります。
    ご注文確定後に、同じ洋書の販売価格が変動しても、それは反映されません。
  • 製本 Paperback:紙装版/ペーパーバック版/ページ数 350 p.
  • 言語 ENG
  • 商品コード 9789401178273
  • DDC分類 330

Full Description

During the last decade, the econometric study of investment behaviour has developed from the descriptive construction of empirical investment equations, as first performed by J. Tinbergen in his well-known 19- publication: 'A Method and its Application to Investment Activity', to the empirical testing of increasingly explicit theories of production behaviour. It was principally D. Jorgenson who gave a great push to this intensified interest in micro-economic investment, with his famous 1965-paper: 'Anticipation and Investment Behaviour', in which he formulated a pure neoclassical model of investment behaviour under the conditions of a (simple) homogeneous production technology and perfectly competi­ tive markets. But, although the scope of the familiar flexible accelerator model was considerably extended by the introduction of relative factor prices, the resulting investment relationship generally remained one of the most ill-estimated equations in econometric models. The very rigid assumptions of pure neoclassical models might have caused these bad results. More­ over, the required ex post measure for aggregate capital stock is very deficient for most economies. Hence, it should be interesting to formulate investment models subject to less rigid restrictions on production and market behaviour and, preferably, not containing any measure of aggre­ gate capital stock.

Contents

1. Some remarks on the concept of a production function.- 1.1 The Production Function.- 1.2 The Input (Level) Set.- 1.3 The Relationship between Production Functions and Input (Level) Sets.- 1.4 Transforms of Production Functions.- 1.5 Homogeneous and homothetic Production Functions.- 1.6 Substitutability in neoclassical Production Functions.- 1.7 Some particular neoclassical Production Functions.- 1.8 Technical Progress in neoclassical and vintage Production Functions.- 1.9 Conclusion.- 2. Investment behaviour based on micro production models.- 2.0 Introduction.- 2.1 A putty-putty ces-Investment Model.- 2.2 A putty-clay ces-Investment Model.- 2.3 A non-vintage ces-Investment Model.- 2.4 A putty-putty ves-Investment Model.- 2.5 A putty-clay ves-Investment Model.- 2.6 A non-vintage ves-Investment Model.- 2.7 An Adjustment Cost Model for the Investment Demand.- 2.8 Conclusion.- 3. The aggregation problem: the utilization of micro-relationships for macro-data.- 3.1 Functional Separability.- 3.2 Deterministic Aggregation.- 3.3 Bias in Deterministic Aggregation.- 3.4 Stochastic Aggregation.- 3.5 Conclusion.- 4. An application on postwar investment behaviour of six eec-countries.- 4.0 Introduction.- 4.1 Belgium.- 4.2 France.- 4.3 Germany (Federal Republic).- 4.4 Great Britain (inclusive Northern Ireland).- 4.5 Italy.- 4.6 Netherlands.- 4.7 Conclusion.- A.1 Derivation of the Class of CES-Production Functions.- Appendix B. Necessary conditions for the supremum of the functional (II.1.6).- Appendix C. Optimal control problems with an infinite time horizon.- Appendix D. The investment relationships discussed.- List of Symbols.

最近チェックした商品